Freeman

ARTICLE

A Tax Deduction for Education

Should the Tax Laws Favor Public Schools?

JUNE 01, 1994 by SHELDON RICHMAN, ROY CORDATO

There is something fundamentally unfair about being penalized for choosing a private school or homeschooling for one’s children. The penalty, of course, is that parents who wish to find alternatives to public schools must pay for education twice, first through local taxes and then through tuition or homeschooling expenses.

In light of the recent defeat of the Proposition 174 school-choice initiative in California, perhaps it is time to rethink the school-choice strategy. Even among advocates of choice, there have been those who have had doubts about educational vouchers. For decades they have warned that vouchers would be seen as a state subsidy to private schools and that that perception would be used to rationalize regulations from which private schools today are exempt. How, it will be asked, can “the public’s money” be permitted to go to just anyone who starts a school? Most people won’t think it should be allowed. Thus, they will accept as reasonable an array of regulations governing the hiring of teachers and curriculum.

Advocates of vouchers are aware of that criticism, and they tried to prevent new regulation in Prop 174. But that may have been its undoing. The Economist commented that the initiative “might well have passed if it had simply contained provisions requiring schools that received voucher money to meet some basic standards set by the authorities.”

If so, advocates of vouchers who are concerned with the integrity of private schooling face a dilemma. What if the only voucher plan that has a chance of passing would make the private schools virtual carbon copies of the public schools? Surely, passing such a plan would not be worth the effort.

What is needed is an alternative that cannot be mistaken for a subsidy, that cannot be used to rationalize regulation of private schools, and that will give parents at least some control over which schools their children attend.

A federal income tax deduction for private educational expenses would satisfy those criteria. Under this proposal, parents who finance their children’s education directly from their own pockets would do so with pre-tax dollars. Similar to the way people contribute to an Individual Retirement Account, all parents could take advantage of this device, even if they do not itemize tax deductions. The deduction could also be available to those who paid for someone else’s children’s education. Tax-free education savings accounts would be another way to accomplish the same goal. Educational expenses would include tuition for any sectarian or secular private school and outlays for homeschooling.

Critics might object that an education deduction would be a subsidy because it would lower the relative cost of private education. But economic analysis suggests otherwise. Such a deduction should not be considered a subsidy but the amelioration of a general tax penalty on savings and investment. When businesses are allowed to deduct from their taxable income those expenditures intended to produce future income, those deductions are not considered a subsidy. The economics of tax policy argues that all investment expenditures, whether made by businesses or individuals, should be treated in that manner; today they clearly are not.

While some personal financial investments are not penalized (IRAs, and other retirement saving vehicles, for example), educational expenses are. Yet everyone from teachers’ union president Albert Shanker to Milton Friedman acknowledges that education is an investment with some expected return. Its purpose is to enhance the future productivity and income of students. Thus, principles of efficient tax policy suggest that all personal expenditures on education, whether by parents for their children’s primary, secondary, or higher education, or by adults for continuing education, should be made with pretax dollars. And since an education deduction is not a subsidy, there could be no reasonable church-state objection to including religious-based schooling.

A tax code that does not permit deductions for investment, including education, is biased against it. That seeming paradox—that apparently equal tax treatment of consumption and investment is in fact unequal treatment—is easily resolved.

Imagine Jane Smith is deciding what to do with the $1,000 she has just earned. She will compare the satisfaction she can obtain from direct consumption, say, buying a big-screen television, with the future income that could be generated by investing the money in a certificate of deposit (CD) at a bank. If the $1,000 is taxed at 28 percent, both the returns to consumption (the size of the television) and the returns to investment are reduced. But the tax will reduce the investment returns a second time, because the interest on the CD will also be taxed. In that way, the income tax penalizes investment more heavily than it does consumption and therefore biases Jane’s decision against purchasing the CD. Were Jane allowed to buy the CD with pretax income, the tax penalty would be eliminated. It is that logic that supports business deductions for capital expenditures, including payments for employees’ education, from taxable income. By forcing educational investment to be made with after-tax income, the government penalizes such expenditures in the same way it does Jane’s CD investment.

What’s Fair

Economics aside, the critics might persist in their belief that the tax deduction somehow would be unfair. But in a free society, the fairness argument cuts the other way. As a matter of principle, letting parents keep more of their own money to educate their children should not be thought of as unfair. The claim that such a deduction would be unfair is based on the premise that the government is entitled to all our income and that anything it lets us keep is a subsidy. That’s an un-American idea to say the least.

Far from being unfair, the deduction would actually create a more even-handed treatment of educational spending. Most public schools are supported by property taxes. Property taxes are tax deductible. Thus, parents’ expenditures on public schooling are tax deductible. But their expenditures on other forms of education are not. Our proposal would remove that bias by extending the deduction to alternative schooling.

A middle-class family in the 28 percent bracket that spent $5,000 for private-school tuition would save $1,400 in federal taxes, plus perhaps $500 more in state and local income taxes. That is not as much as the $2,500 that Prop 174 would have provided, but for some families it could be the margin of affordability between public and private school. The tax relief would not be as great for families in a lower bracket, although it might be enough to stimulate the launching of low-cost neighborhood private schools. The deduction might also prompt some parents to consider homeschooling, which more and more families are finding to be the best alternative of all.

Finally, it may be asked, why shouldn’t the tax laws favor the public schools? They should not, because in a free society and an uncertain world, people should not be unreasonably restricted in the trial-and-error process of raising their children and improving themselves to the best of their ability. Public school administrators do not have a monopoly on wisdom. Parents and alternative providers may have a better idea. Free individuals should be able to face life’s challenges with the widest latitude—and without being penalized by the tax code for doing so.

ASSOCIATED ISSUE

June 1994

ABOUT

SHELDON RICHMAN

Sheldon Richman is the former editor of The Freeman and TheFreemanOnline.org, and a contributor to The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics. He is the author of Separating School and State: How to Liberate America's Families.

ABOUT

ROY CORDATO

Roy Cordato is the Vice President for Research and resident scholar at the John Locke Foundation. He is a member of the Mont Pelerin Society and the former executive board member of The Association of Private Enterprise Education. He holds an M.A. in urban and regional economics from the University of Hartford and a Ph.D. in economics from George Mason University.

comments powered by Disqus

EMAIL UPDATES

* indicates required
Sign me up for...

CURRENT ISSUE

July/August 2014

The United States' corporate tax burden is the highest in the world, but innovators will always find a way to duck away from Uncle Sam's reach. Doug Bandow explains how those with the means are renouncing their citizenship in increasing numbers, while J. Dayne Girard describes the innovative use of freeports to shield wealth from the myriad taxes and duties imposed on it as it moves around the world. Of course the politicians brand all of these people unpatriotic, hoping you won't think too hard about the difference between the usual crony-capitalist suspects and the global creative elite that have done so much to improve our lives. In a special tech section, Joseph Diedrich, Thomas Bogle, and Matthew McCaffrey look at various ways these innovators add value to our lives--even in ways they probably never expected.
Download Free PDF

PAST ISSUES

SUBSCRIBE

RENEW YOUR SUBSCRIPTION