Freeman

BOOK REVIEW

The Gridlock Economy: How Too Much Ownership Wrecks Markets, Stops Innovation, and Costs Lives

AUGUST 19, 2009 by ART CARDEN

Without private property rights, people have incentives to overuse an asset. Conflicting private property rights, on the other hand, create a “tragedy of the anti-commons” in which resources are underused, according to Michael Heller. In The Gridlock Economy, he treats the reader to a compelling array of examples of the tragedy of the anti-commons in practice, from conflicting rights to the electromagnetic spectrum to problems assembling the rights necessary to expand airports to the ways innovation is slowed by the need to assemble bundles of patents.

Heller, who teaches property-law courses at Columbia Law School, summarizes his point this way: “Gridlock is a free market paradox. When too many people own pieces of one thing, cooperation breaks down, wealth disappears, and everybody loses.” I’m not convinced that this is really a “free market paradox.” If anything, gridlock is a state failure rather than a market failure.

The book’s main contribution to the literature on property rights and institutions is to show that private ownership is a necessary but not sufficient condition for the market to work its magic. When many people have private property rights that allow them to exercise veto power over more valuable projects, wealth dissipates because bargaining is dominated by holdup problems. Russian privatizations, for example, split rights across too many parties and erected veto points that created anti-commons resources.

Heller offers a wide-ranging discussion of regulatory pathologies leading to “gridlock,” particularly in the ways intellectual property is regulated in the biotechnology industry. He doesn’t, however, answer a question I had throughout the book. If it’s clear, as he says, that regulation cannot keep up with innovation (as we’ve seen in technology, medicine, and most recently high finance), why should we trust the state to regulate further? As a Hayekian, I’m skeptical of the notion that regulators can have the information they need to get the market as it is to function as it does on the blackboard in economics 101.

Since outside observers can’t articulate a theory of rights or a structure of institutions that will “work” a priori, it stands to reason that legal institutions should be flexible so as to allow for innovation across fields. While Heller looks for new ways to design institutions, perhaps we should find better ways to let these institutions evolve.

Heller notes that “judicial and political battles are overtaking the academic research” and that Congress is considering serious overhaul of the patent-law infrastructure. But will that solve the “gridlock” problem? Why should we expect members of Congress to know how intellectual property in biotech should be structured? We shouldn’t. I am afraid that Heller is too caught up in what James Buchanan calls “the romance of politics,” expecting politicians to solve problems of their own making.

It would be the height of folly for me as an economist in Memphis to presume to know how intricately detailed contracts in biotech firms should be structured, but we can see some of the pathologies of regulation in a dynamic economy emerging in high-tech enterprises. For example, Heller notes that the Federal Trade Commission arbitrarily dissolved the patent pool for laser eye surgery. He also points out a disturbing trend that deserves further investigation: “In telecom, competitors know that often the most profitable approach is not to innovate, but to stop others from investing.” He’s right. Patent law is often used in a rent-seeking fashion that burdens real innovators, but that has nothing to do with any market failure. Our system of intellectual property is a creature of the government.

Among the causes of gridlock Heller identifies is antitrust law. He writes, “For biotech pooling to have any chance, Congress may need to create special antitrust rules.” He seems not to see how such rules will be hard to adapt to further innovations. And again, he is too trusting of politicians to tinker with legislation to solve a problem. Outright repeal of the antitrust laws would be a much better move, solving numerous problems all at once.

There is much in The Gridlock Economy that could be explored in greater detail, but these are directions for further research rather than criticisms of the thesis. I expect that the book will find its way onto reading lists across campuses worldwide. It offers much food for thought, but readers should think skeptically about Heller’s eagerness to have politicians solve problems that are mostly if not entirely of their own making, not the free market’s.

ASSOCIATED ISSUE

September 2009

ABOUT

ART CARDEN

Art Carden teaches economics at Samford University.

comments powered by Disqus

EMAIL UPDATES

* indicates required
Sign me up for...

CURRENT ISSUE

July/August 2014

The United States' corporate tax burden is the highest in the world, but innovators will always find a way to duck away from Uncle Sam's reach. Doug Bandow explains how those with the means are renouncing their citizenship in increasing numbers, while J. Dayne Girard describes the innovative use of freeports to shield wealth from the myriad taxes and duties imposed on it as it moves around the world. Of course the politicians brand all of these people unpatriotic, hoping you won't think too hard about the difference between the usual crony-capitalist suspects and the global creative elite that have done so much to improve our lives. In a special tech section, Joseph Diedrich, Thomas Bogle, and Matthew McCaffrey look at various ways these innovators add value to our lives--even in ways they probably never expected.
Download Free PDF

PAST ISSUES

SUBSCRIBE

RENEW YOUR SUBSCRIPTION