Freeman

PERSPECTIVE

What Does the Oil Spill Prove?

AUGUST 25, 2010 by SHELDON RICHMAN

You’ve got to hand it to the people who dislike free markets. They see them everywhere, especially wherever any serious problem arises. That no free market exists within a thousand miles makes no difference whatsoever.

Take the oil spill in the Gulf. Market opponents are having a field day. They say this finally demonstrates the need for government to run things. Private firms can’t be trusted.

But it looks more like government can’t be trusted. The central government is, in law and in fact, the owner of the part in the Gulf where BP drilled for oil. (I did not say it is the legitimate owner.) The owner leased its property to a private company, BP, with a bad safety record, issued permits for the drilling operation, and required the company to use the government’s own flawed models in preparing for spills. It then failed to keep a sharp eye on what BP and subcontractors Transocean and Halliburton were doing to its property. That might have something to do with the fact that government regulators don’t have the sort of relationship to “their” property that normal private owners do, and they can always be counted on to get friendly with those they regulate. The Minerals Management Service in the Interior Department has a special conflict of interest: It makes money off the drilling it permits and regulates. Thus it could benefit from decisions that are bad for the public.

So what failed here, the market or the State? The call isn’t even close. The free market was nowhere near the scene. It has an airtight alibi: It didn’t exist.

Now you might get a die-hard anti-market person to concede this. So we move to the next step. What should replace the current hybrid (government-corporate) system? I see only two choices: full government management or full market management. Full government management wouldn’t appear terribly promising, considering that the current problems are traceable back to government management. How would things change substantially if, instead of contracting out the drilling to a nominally private company, the government instead hired the personnel itself and paid them directly from the U.S. Treasury? Who cares if the rig says “BP,” “Transocean,” or “U.S. Government” on it? The same fallible people would be in the same position to make the same fateful mistakes. Not much would change.

That’s because what matters is incentives, not whether a worker is on the government payroll. Why assume that civil service employees know or care more than people paid by corporations?

But, it will be said, government workers will have a mandate to protect the environment and the public. Okay, let’s go with that. Let’s say the decision-makers are environmental hawks who really don’t like oil drilling anywhere. They’ll be tough: no drilling unless it’s 100 percent safe. Leaving aside the obvious problem with this standard, that policy would have costs. The risk of oil spills may drop to zero, but we might have to forgo certain important benefits in the process. Poor people, say, might have their prospects dimmed by more expensive energy.

Is the tradeoff worth it? How do we go about answering that question? Government is no help here. It can certainly impose a plan, but constructing a plan beneficial to the public would be like playing darts in the dark. Mises and Hayek covered this in their writings on State socialism and economic calculation.

Things are sure looking bleak. Government assurances are worthless whether it contracts out for drilling or does it itself. That leaves only the free market. Can it be trusted?

First off, let’s remember that we live in the real world. There are no iron-clad guarantees. The best we can hope for is relative security. When people conclude that government management is the best alternative, knowingly or not they have rigged the game. They are comparing the messy real world in which free markets would operate to an impossible government-managed utopia, where regulators have complete knowledge and total dedication to the public interest. This is the Nirvana Fallacy.

Only two options are on the table: an arrangement where incentives align economic activity with the public interest and one where they don’t. Now which setup seems more promising? One where personnel risk no capital, face no prospects of bankruptcy, and procure their revenue by force (taxation) after flattering members of special-interest-serving congressmen? Or one where capital has to be raised from wary investors in a competitive environment, insurance is priced according to risk, products have to be sold to buyers who are free to say no, and full and strict liability haunts every decision, with bankruptcy always looming and no government bailout even implied?

When you come down to it, the choice is really rather easy.

* * *

The fiscal fiasco we’re mired in is driving “responsible” heads to search for new sources of revenue, among them the value-added tax. It’s an idea whose time should never come, Roy Cordato writes.

The Fourth Amendment appears to enshrine the right to privacy against government intrusion. But it hasn’t quite worked out that way, according to research by Joseph Stromberg.

How can a nation of immigrants be so down on immigration? Aeon Skoble has some explanations.

We often assume the Founding Fathers would be spinning in their graves if they knew what’s going on in the United States. But probably not Alexander Hamilton, Nicholas Curott and Tyler Watts suggest.

A new era of financial regulation is upon us. Chidem Kurdas has the details of what’s been cooked up by some of the chefs who prepared the last collapsed soufflé.

Predicting the future is big business, but why do most prognosticators get it so wrong? Steven Horwitz applies some good economics and comes up with an answer.

The record of government regulation is consistently bad. Robert L. Bradley, Jr., and Richard W. Fulmer give us 15 reasons why this has to be the case.

From our columnists: Donald Boudreaux examines the language for bias. Stephen Davies detects a return of the economic way of thinking. David Henderson assesses the state of civil liberties. John Stossel laments the destruction of property rights. And Charles Johnson, confronting the assertion that opposing civil rights legislation means opposing civil rights, responds, “It Just Ain’t So!”

Books on animal spirits, a black entrepreneur, free trade, and Marbury v. Madison are evaluated by our reviewers.

—Sheldon Richman, Editor
srichman@fee.org

ASSOCIATED ISSUE

September 2010

ABOUT

SHELDON RICHMAN

Sheldon Richman is the former editor of The Freeman and TheFreemanOnline.org, and a contributor to The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics. He is the author of Separating School and State: How to Liberate America's Families.

comments powered by Disqus

EMAIL UPDATES

* indicates required
Sign me up for...

CURRENT ISSUE

September 2014

For centuries, hierarchical models dominated human organizations. Kings, warlords, and emperors could rally groups--but also oppress them. Non-hierarchical forms of organization, though, are increasingly defining our lives. It's no secret how this shift has benefited out social lives, including dating, and it's becoming more commonplace even in the corporate world. But it has also now come even to organizations bent on domination rather than human flourishing, as the Islamic State shows. If even destructive groups rely on this form of entrepreneurial organization, then hierarchy's time could truly be coming to an end.
Download Free PDF

PAST ISSUES

SUBSCRIBE

RENEW YOUR SUBSCRIPTION